<![CDATA[Hedgehogs.net: '' related content]]> http://www.hedgehogs.net/tag/economic+theories?view=rss http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11468233/published-preprint-international-rampd-spillovers-and-other-unobserved-common-spillovers-and-shocks-arxiv150206805v1-qfinec Thu, 26 Feb 2015 19:38:55 +0000 http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11468233/published-preprint-international-rampd-spillovers-and-other-unobserved-common-spillovers-and-shocks-arxiv150206805v1-qfinec <![CDATA[Published / Preprint: International R&amp;D Spillovers and other Unobserved Common Spillovers and Shocks. (arXiv:1502.06805v1 [q-fin.EC])]]>

Studies which are based on Coe and Helpman (1995) and use weighted foreign R&D variables to estimate channel-specific R&D spillovers disregard the interaction between international R&D spillovers and other unobserved common spillovers and shocks. Using a panel of 50 economies from 1970-2011, we find that disregarding this interaction leads to inconsistent estimates whenever knowledge spillovers and other unobserved effects are correlated with foreign and domestic R&D. When this interaction is modeled, estimates are consistent; however, they confound foreign and domestic R&D effects with unobserved effects. Thus, the coefficient of a weighted foreign R&D variable cannot capture genuine channel-specific R&D spillovers.

read more...

]]>
11468233
http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11466043/musical-chairs Thu, 19 Feb 2015 14:24:39 +0000 http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11466043/musical-chairs <![CDATA[Musical chairs]]>

read more...

]]>
11466043
http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11464012/store-of-value Thu, 19 Feb 2015 04:40:47 +0000 http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11464012/store-of-value <![CDATA[Store of Value]]> If I had my druthers, politics would be kept a safe distance apart from economic analysis. The economics profession, however, is guided by a policymaking focus. Economists are compelled to choose sides ...

]]>
11464012
http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11459801/fed-study-shows-persistent-fed-overoptimism-about-economic-growth-what-will-they-do-about-it Tue, 03 Feb 2015 22:39:45 +0000 http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11459801/fed-study-shows-persistent-fed-overoptimism-about-economic-growth-what-will-they-do-about-it <![CDATA[Fed Study Shows "Persistent Fed Overoptimism about Economic Growth"; What Will They Do About It?]]>
In an attempt to explain, a new Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco dives into the Persistent Overoptimism about Economic Growth.

My friend "BC" commented "It has taken 7-8 years for Fed economists to get around to this brilliant insight."

I provide the real reasons following this excerpt from the report ...
Since 2007, Federal Open Market Committee participants have been persistently too optimistic about future U.S. economic growth. Real GDP growth forecasts have typically started high, but then are revised down over time as the incoming data continue to disappoint. Possible explanations for this pattern include missed warning signals about the buildup of imbalances before the crisis, overestimation of the efficacy of monetary policy following a balance-sheet recession, and the natural tendency of forecasters to extrapolate from recent data.




Explaining the persistent overoptimism

Economic forecasting can be a humbling endeavor. In a cross-country study of private-sector forecasts from 1989 to 1998, Loungani (2001) finds that “the record of failure to predict recessions is virtually unblemished.” He also finds that forecast revisions in one direction tend to be followed by further revisions in the same direction and that one-year-ahead growth forecasts are typically too optimistic.

Implications for economic models

Research has identified numerous instances of persistent bias in the track records of professional forecasters. These findings apply not only to forecasts of growth, but also of inflation and unemployment (Coibion and Gorodnichencko 2012). Overall, the evidence raises doubts about the theory of “rational expectations.” This theory, which is the dominant paradigm in macroeconomics, assumes that peoples’ forecasts exhibit no systematic bias towards optimism or pessimism. Allowing for departures from rational expectations in economic models would be a way to more accurately capture features of real-world behavior

An updated study by Ahir and Loungani (2014) finds that the private-sector’s record of failure to predict recessions remained intact through 2008 and 2009. A study by Alessi, et al. (2014) finds that one-year-ahead growth forecasts from the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and the European Central Bank from 2008 to 2012 exhibited substantial overoptimism, averaging 1.6 to 2.4 percentage points above actual growth. The SEP growth forecasts fit the pattern of these various studies.
What Will They Do About It?

That question is easy to answer: absolutely nothing. There is a systemic bias towards optimism from economists in general, not just central banks.

I have mentioned that numerous times in recent years, even after it was long understood the recession of 2007-2009 was a balance-sheet recession.

For example, on January 6, I noted Economists Upbeat Despite 4th Consecutive Decline in Factory Orders; Auto Orders vs. Expectations.
Economists are among the most optimistic groups on the planet. Year in, year out they project improvements in growth.

So today, despite 4th Consecutive Decline in Factory Orders, it's no surprise that economists remain optimistic.
Private Pep Rally

On January 29, Fed Chair Janet Yellen met with Senate Democrats at a private luncheon. She told the Democrats that the U.S. Economy is Strong.

“She went through the issues of unemployment and inflation. Very positive. And economic growth numbers were good, have been good. There’s work to be done,” Sen. Richard Durbin (D-Ill.) said after the luncheon.

Could the Fed be rear-view mirror forecasting once again? I think so. Third quarter GDP rebounded strongly, so Yellen did what economists do, project strength into the future. Somehow this tendency is one-sided. Economists seldom project weakness the same way.

Diving Into the Details

On January 31, I went Diving Into the 4th Quarter GDP Report and noticed some ominous trends.

On February 1, I made a pretty bold statement Canada in Recession, US Will Follow in 2015.

Today, I noted Total Construction Spending Weaker Than Expected; Residential Construction Spending in Contraction.

Also today, but something I did not comment on, U.S. Consumer Spending in December Weakest Since 2009.
U.S. consumer spending recorded its biggest decline since late 2009 in December with households saving the extra cash from cheaper gasoline.

Other data on Monday showed factory activity cooled in January, suggesting the economy may have entered the new year on a slightly softer footing than had been expected.

Nevertheless, upbeat and cash-flush consumers are expected to step-up spending and buoy the economy this year.

"The consumer is poised to do well in early 2015. Lower gasoline prices are going to provide a big lift to consumption," said Ryan Sweet, a senior economist at Moody's Analytics in West Chester, Pennsylvania.
Reasons for Optimism

  1. Missed warning signals about the buildup of imbalances before the crisis
  2. Overestimation of the efficacy of monetary policy following a balance-sheet recession
  3. Natural tendency of forecasters to extrapolate from recent data. 

Comment on Reason #1

Bernanke like Greenspan could not see the obvious. This is a general statement. Buildup of imbalances has nothing to do with it. Neither Greenspan nor Bernanke could spot bubbles.

Janet Yellen right now is virtually blind as a bat. She cannot see the bubbles in bonds and equities the Fed created. When those bubbles burst, the slowdown should smack some sense into the Fed, but it won't. Moreover, the bigger this equity bubble gets, the bigger the crash. The Fed cannot see that either.

Comment on Reason #2

These arrogant fools actually believe they are economic wizards who can steer the economy like a truck on a highway. The idea that central banks can set interest rates is as faulty as Russian central planners can correctly set the price of oranges. But that's what they believe.

Comment on Reason #3

They are extrapolating 3rd quarter GDP into the future again right now. They miss the bond and equity bubbles, factory orders, and countless other things. All strong reports are thought to be representative. All weak reports are deemed to be a "soft patch".

Judging from the "strong economy" statement of Yellen, the Fed seems to believe the US will "decouple" from the clearly slowing global economy. It has for a while, but it cannot last.

Too Much Faith in Models

Here is the first of two bonus reasons to help explain overoptimism:

The Fed (economists in general) have far too much faith in economic models and far too little common sense. The economy cannot be driven like a truck. Fat tails appear far more than theory suggests. Why? Because many widely-held theories are complete nonsense.

Anyone recall the widespread belief people would not walk away from their homes? And what about the idiotic Keynesian theory that recessions and inflation could not happen at the same time.

Economists widely believed that bit of nonsense. Yet, instead of abandoning Keynesian theories, they went further down the rabbit hole to explain things.

System Runs on Lies

Here's a final bonus explanation the San Francisco Fed failed to mention: Good news sells. People do not like the truth. They would rather hear lies. And the Fed is willing to provide lies, especially in difficult times.

The entire system runs on lies such as

  • Pro-forma data
  • Beat-the-street nonsense where corporations provide analysts with numbers the corporations know they can beat by a penny
  • Analysts are more than willing to downgrade expectations to help corporations beat-the-street

When it Becomes Serious

The Fed does not want an audit? What pray tell does it have to hide?

European politician Jean Claude Juncker summed it up nicely: "When it becomes serious, you have to lie".

And so the Fed does. Sometimes, as a matter of arrogant belief in their own wizardry, they even start to believe the lies they tell.

Mike "Mish" Shedlock
http://globaleconomicanalysis.blogspot.com]]>
11459801
http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11459428/infrastructurespending-benefits-questioned Tue, 03 Feb 2015 20:41:31 +0000 http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11459428/infrastructurespending-benefits-questioned <![CDATA[Infrastructure-Spending Benefits Questioned]]> 11459428 http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11459253/supply-demand-and-equilibrium Tue, 03 Feb 2015 19:52:03 +0000 http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11459253/supply-demand-and-equilibrium <![CDATA[Supply, demand, and equilibrium]]>

From Marginal Revolution University, three short videos on the economic concepts of supply, demand, and equilibrium using oil as an example good.

read more...

]]>
11459253
http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11458767/economic-theory-summer-camp Tue, 03 Feb 2015 18:14:21 +0000 http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11458767/economic-theory-summer-camp <![CDATA[Economic Theory Summer Camp]]> Grad students with an interest in economic theory should click here.

]]>
11458767
http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11458204/is-democratic-keynesianism-possible Tue, 03 Feb 2015 16:43:00 +0000 http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11458204/is-democratic-keynesianism-possible <![CDATA[Is democratic Keynesianism possible?]]>

Simon calls for fiscal policy to be set independently of government, to prevent it "being corrupted by politics and ideology." This might seem like pointy-headed technocracy. In fact, it is more radical than that.

read more...

]]>
11458204
http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11457573/ifdp20151127-monetary-policy-trend-inflation-and-the-great-moderation-an-alternative-interpretation-comment Mon, 02 Feb 2015 19:37:41 +0000 http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11457573/ifdp20151127-monetary-policy-trend-inflation-and-the-great-moderation-an-alternative-interpretation-comment <![CDATA[IFDP2015-1127: Monetary Policy, Trend Inflation and the Great Moderation: An Alternative Interpretation - Comment]]> 11457573 http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11454672/house-prices-better-seasonal-adjustment-real-prices-and-pricetorent-ratio-in-november Thu, 29 Jan 2015 10:57:35 +0000 http://www.hedgehogs.net/pg/newsfeeds/hhwebadmin/item/11454672/house-prices-better-seasonal-adjustment-real-prices-and-pricetorent-ratio-in-november <![CDATA[House Prices: Better Seasonal Adjustment; Real Prices and Price-to-Rent Ratio in November]]> This morning, S&P reported that the National index increased 0.8% in October seasonally adjusted. However, it appears the seasonal adjustment has been distorted by the high level of distressed sales in recent years. Trulia's Jed Kolko wrote in August: "Let’s Improve, Not Ignore, Seasonal Adjustment of Housing Data"
The housing crisis substantially changed the seasonal pattern of housing activity: relative to conventional home sales, which peak in summer, distressed home sales are more evenly spread throughout the year and sell at a discount. As a result, in years when distressed sales constitute a larger share of overall sales, the seasonal swings in home prices get bigger while the seasonal swings in sales volumes get smaller.

Sharply changing seasonal patterns create problems for seasonal adjustment methods, which typically estimate seasonal adjustment factors by averaging several years’ worth of observed seasonal patterns. A sharp but ultimately temporary change in the seasonal pattern for housing activity affects seasonal adjustment factors more gradually and for more years than it should. Despite the recent normalizing of the housing market, seasonal adjustment factors are still based, in part, on patterns observed at the height of the foreclosure crisis, causing home price indices to be over-adjusted in some months and under-adjusted in others.
Better House Price Seasonal AdjustmentKolko proposed a better seasonal adjustment:

This graph from Kolko shows the weighted seasonal adjustment (see Kolko's article for a description of his method). Kolko calculates that prices increased 0.6% on a weighted seasonal adjustment basis in November - as opposed to the 0.8% SA increase and 0.1% NSA decrease reported by Case-Shiller.

The "better" SA (green) shows prices are still increasing, but more slowly than the Case-Shiller SA.

The expected slowdown in year-over-year price increases is ongoing. In November 2013, the Comp 20 index was up 13.8% year-over-year (YoY). Now the index is only up 4.3% YoY. This is the smallest YoY increase since October 2012 (the National index was up 10.9% YoY in October 2013, is now up 4.7% - a little more than the YoY change last month).

Looking forward, I expect the YoY increases for the indexes to move more sideways (as opposed to down).  Two points: 1) I don't expect the indexes to turn negative YoY (in 2015) , and 2) I think most of the slowdown on a YoY basis is now behind us. This slowdown in price increases was expected by several key analysts, and I think it is good news for housing and the economy.

In the earlier post, I graphed nominal house prices, but it is also important to look at prices in real terms (inflation adjusted).  Case-Shiller, CoreLogic and others report nominal house prices.  As an example, if a house price was $200,000 in January 2000, the price would be close to $277,000 today adjusted for inflation (39%).  That is why the second graph below is important - this shows "real" prices (adjusted for inflation).

Another point on real prices: In the Case-Shiller release this morning, the National Index was reported as being 9.1% below the bubble peak.   However, in real terms, the National index is still about 23% below the bubble peak.

Nominal House Prices

Nominal House PricesThe first graph shows the monthly Case-Shiller National Index SA, the monthly Case-Shiller Composite 20 SA, and the CoreLogic House Price Indexes (through November) in nominal terms as reported.

In nominal terms, the Case-Shiller National index (SA) is back to April 2005 levels, and the Case-Shiller Composite 20 Index (SA) is back to November 2004 levels, and the CoreLogic index (NSA) is back to February 2005.

Real House Prices

Real House PricesThe second graph shows the same three indexes in real terms (adjusted for inflation using CPI less Shelter). Note: some people use other inflation measures to adjust for real prices.

In real terms, the National index is back to March 2003 levels, the Composite 20 index is back to September 2002, and the CoreLogic index back to March 2003.

In real terms, house prices are back to early '00s levels.

Price-to-Rent

In October 2004, Fed economist John Krainer and researcher Chishen Wei wrote a Fed letter on price to rent ratios: House Prices and Fundamental Value. Kainer and Wei presented a price-to-rent ratio using the OFHEO house price index and the Owners' Equivalent Rent (OER) from the BLS.

Price-to-Rent RatioHere is a similar graph using the Case-Shiller National, Composite 20 and CoreLogic House Price Indexes.

This graph shows the price to rent ratio (January 1998 = 1.0).

On a price-to-rent basis, the Case-Shiller National index is back to April 2003 levels, the Composite 20 index is back to October 2002 levels, and the CoreLogic index is back to April 2003.

In real terms, and as a price-to-rent ratio, prices are mostly back to early 2000 levels - and maybe moving a little sideways now.

]]>
11454672